Blog

Agricultural Economics Journals

For the professional agricultural economists out there, you might want to take a look at my latest President's column in the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association (AAEA) Exchange.

Here's a preview:

There have been some dramatic changes in the publishing landscape for authors of journal articles in agricultural and applied economics. However, my sense is that these changes are not widely known or acknowledged. As a result, the AAEA and some of our “sister” associations have been caught a bit flat footed. Despite the fact that the publishing landscape has dramatically changed in the past decade, some core aspects of the AAEA’s journal offerings have remained static. If we want to continue to serve our members and remain a source for key research in agricultural and applied economics, some change is likely warranted.

The whole thing is here.  I'll also emphasis the closing call for feedback and input:

More broadly, the aforementioned changes have prompted the board to consider whether and how the AAEA might increase the supply of journal articles published under the Association’s banner either through existing outlets or perhaps through a new one entirely. We are in the beginning stages of thinking about how to respond to these structural changes in the publishing landscape. I’d appreciate hearing your thoughts and suggestions.

Country of Origin Labeling and Cattle Imports

My post from back in November about the (lack of a) relationship between the repeal of mandatory country of origin labeling (MCOOL) and cattle prices seems to have been receiving a lot of attention lately.  A main driver seems to be that Tomi Lahren, a conservative journalist with a large social media following, again promoted the idea that MCOOL was a cause of declining cattle prices in a video interview with R-CALF's CEO.  For a summary of the controversy see this article by Carrie Stadheim in the Tri-State Livestock News. 

I won't re-adjudicate my original arguments as you can read them for yourself.  However, I do want to bring some data to bear on an additional claim that has been made in relation to MCOOL and cattle prices.  The article in the Tri-State Livestock News contains a quote that seems to be attributed to me, but I said nothing of the sort.  I presume, instead, the "he" in quote below is the R-CALF CEO.  Here's the quote:

“Without COOL…meatpackers can reach out and source live cattle and beef from 20 countries, bring it into the US, sell it to unsusepecting consumers with a US inspection sticker on it, even though it comes from a foreign source and consumers don’t know the difference,” he said.

So, let's take a look at the implication of this argument.  We repeal MCOOL, and now meatpackers turn to the 20 countries and import more meat.  And, presumably, this caused the decline in cattle prices?

Well, here is USDA data on meat and veal imports to the US and on live cattle imports to the US.  The solid black line is the date of the repeal of MCOOL.

There was an uptick in live cattle imports right after repeal of MCOOL but then an even more dramatic decline.  Overall the above figure suggests no discernible impact of MCOOL on US imports of beef or cattle.  If I look at the total imports the first 11 months of 2015 prior to repeal of MOOL and compare it to the first 11 months of 2016 after the repeal of MCOOL (I use the first 11 months because the December 2016 data is not yet out), I find that, if anything, US imports of beef and cattle are, in fact, down after the repeal of MCOOL by 369 million pounds and by 297,290 head, respectively.   

Here's the thing.  Yes, it is true that: "meatpackers can reach out and source live cattle and beef from 20 countries, bring it into the US".  But, all those countries selling meat to the US can sell it instead to dozens and dozens of other countries instead.  And, why would these countries try to sell more meat to the US when prices are down in this country?  They wouldn't and the didn't.  

In any event, the point of all this isn't to argue for or against MCOOL.  Rather, I'm simply trying to make sure the claims being made about MCOOL mesh with the best evidence we have, and that evidence suggests that repealing MCOOL seems to have had very little effect on cattle prices.  Attention would be better focused on other issues to help ranchers and cattle producers who are currently experiencing financial hardship.  

Is bigger safer?

The answer to the question in the title, at least in the context of consolidation and food safety, seems to be "no" according to this article by Anne Kim in Washington Monthly.

The subtitle of the article indicates:

A consolidated food industry brings you salad and chicken nuggets cheaper—and spreads deadly food-borne pathogens farther.

And later in the article:

In other words, the same hyperefficient distribution system that brings you convenient and affordable salad greens and all the chicken nuggets you can eat can just as efficiently deliver E. coli, salmonella, and other dangerous bugs to your plate. Moreover, today’s industrialized food production processes carry other public health risks.

The article contains several interesting stories and interviews, but lacks solid evidence supporting the article's main premise that a less consolidated food system would be a safer one.  Yes, there has been consolidation in agriculture.  Yes, when a large firm has a food safety event, it affects more people.  But, what we don't know is whether, overall, a food system with many smaller firms is safer than one with fewer larger firms.  Indeed, the author even acknowledges the following:

According to the CDC, no evidence suggests that smaller or larger producers have an inherent advantage on food safety. “It has to do more with your practices than your size,” says the CDC’s Matthew Wise.

What is not mentioned is that large size can sometimes lower the average (or per unit) cost of investing in certain food safety technologies.  

I touched on this issue in my book, Unnaturally Delicious, when talking to Frank Yiannas, the Vice President of food safety at Walmart.  Here's an excerpt:

More than 120 million Americans (more than a third of the U.S. population) shop at Walmart every week. Does the sheer scale of the operation make the U.S. food system riskier? If Walmart has an outbreak, multitudes would be sickened. Yiannas replied: “One out of every four dollars spent on food are spent at a Walmart. We can make a big difference. Large organizations like Walmart result in a safer food system.” He points out that when Walmart makes a change, it affects the whole system. Sure, smaller companies might have outbreaks that affect fewer people, but when lots of small companies are having lots of small outbreaks, the problem is more widespread. A downside to small companies, said Yiannas, is that they can’t easily invest in improving the system as a whole. While Walmart often attracts negative attention because of its size and scale (e.g., Do they pay workers fairly? Do they hurt local mom-and-pop businesses?), at least in the world of food safety, their size has significant benefits for its customers, and as I’ll soon discuss, even for non-customers.

Yiannas went on to talk about the value of protecting Walmart's brand, the fact that their internal safety standards far exceed government minimums, and he presented evidence that the food safety initiatives that they've implemented have improved safety for the whole country (because of their size). You'll have to read the book for all the details.  

I'll also point out research by Marc Bellemare (here's his piece on the topic in the New York Times) showing a relationship between food safety outbreaks and the prevalence of farmers markets (you know, those places with many small farms and processors).  

I'm not saying that larger IS unilaterally safer, but I am saying there is no solid evidence to support the broad premise behind the Washington Monthly article.  There are a lot things to like about small producers and we ought to think about ways of lowering barriers to entry that are sometimes created by food safety regulations, but doesn't mean we should cast undue fear about our present food system, which is among the safest in the world.  

Food Demand Survey (FooDS) - January 2017

The January 2017 edition of the Food Demand Survey (FooDS) is now out.

After reporting a decline in willingness-to-pay (WTP) for virtually all food products last month, WTP increased for all food products rebounded, with all food products experiencing gains of at least 7%. Steak, deli ham, and chicken wings experienced the largest percent increase in WTP. WTP for both beef products is higher than one year ago, but the opposite was the case for both pork products.

There was a bit of an uptick in reported spending on food away from home, and consumers report expecting higher meat prices in coming weeks relative to last month.  

An ad hoc question was added this month on food waste.  Subjects were shown the following question, which was loosely based on the questions posed by Violeta Stancu and colleagues in this paper published in 2016 in the journal Appetite.  (Note that the order of items was randomized across respondents).  

The most common answer for each item was “hardly any”.

Models were used to estimate the percent of food thrown away each week for each product category. On average, more fresh fruits and vegetables were said to be thrown away than compared to  the other food categories, with 12.7% of this type of food being thrown away. Meat and fish was ranked as the least likely to throw away, with respondents stating only 9.8% of all meat and fish bought was thrown away.


Analysis of demographic data shows (averaged across all food categories), females report about 3 percentage points more food thrown away than men; younger individuals about 10 percentage points more than older consumers; people on SNAP (aka “food stamps”) about 6 percentage points more food is thrown away than by than people not on SNAP; and higher income individuals say they throw away about 5 percentage points more food than lower income individuals.

One of the issues we aim to explore with additional analysis is the extent to which stated food waste behavior is related to risk and time preferences.  

Humpty Dumpty had a great fall

Unless you happen to be relatively low income or one of the few commercial growers, a big change in the grocery store might have gone unnoticed.  Humpty Dumpty didn't exactly fall, but the price of eggs has plunged in recent months.  Here is a recent graph of national retail egg prices (grade A, $/dozen) from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (November 2016 is the last data they report). 

After hovering around $2/dozen for nearly two years, in mid 2015, prices began to rise dramatically, reaching almost $3/dozen in August and September 2015 (a 50% increase).  Then, around the first of 2016, prices began falling.  The fall was even more dramatic than the price increase.  As of November 2016, egg prices were sitting at $1.32/dozen, less than half of what they were a year earlier.

For more perspective, here's the same price data going all the way back to 1980 (this time prices have been adjusted for inflation and are in current dollars).

The above graph illustrates how dramatic the recent swing in egg prices has been in a historical context.  The last time egg prices were as high as the were in September 2015 was 30 years ago in the early 1980s.  And, the last time egg prices were as low as the are today was about 16 years ago in the early 2000s.  

Aside from thinking now  might be a good time to eat an omelet, one might wonder about the causes of recent volatility in egg prices.  While there are no doubt a variety of contributing factors, the main cause has a fairly simple explanation: bird flu.  Back in May 2015, I was writing about the possible impacts of having to kill off almost 40 million hens because of avian influenza.  In fact, looking back on it now, the data show the dramatic impact of the epidemic on the number of table egg laying hens in this country.  

According to USDA data, there were over 313 million hens laying table eggs in December 2014.  Just six months later, there 38.8 million fewer hens, down to 274 million.  Fast forward to today (or at least November 2016, which is the  last reported data), and we're now back up to 309 million hens.  

The change in laying hen inventory over the past couple of years roughly mirrors the changes in egg prices over the same time period, and it is a great example of the economic forces at play.  The bird flu caused a shift in supply (the supply curve shifted up and to the left).  Demand was relatively unchanged, so consumers were left to scramble (sorry I couldn't help myself) over the fewer eggs that remained, bidding up prices.  Because research suggests egg demand is relatively inelastic (i.e., consumers are not very price sensitive when it comes to eggs), a small change in supply can induce much larger proportional change in price.  When the outbreak subsided and producers were able to add back inventory, the same story played out, but this time in reverse.  

It's too soon to tell whether the roller-coaster ride for egg buyers and sellers is over.